查看原文
其他

余永定:A Floor for the Renminbi

2016-01-28 余永定 中国金融四十人论坛

原创声明:本文原载于Project Syndicate网站,作者授权中国金融四十人论坛发布,转载请注明出处。


文/余永定 CF40学术顾问、社科院世界经济与政治研究所研究员


A Floor for the Renminbi


 The People’s Bank of China (PBOC) faces a dilemma. After nearly a decade of trying to curb expectations of continued currency appreciation (spurred by China’s current- and capital-account surpluses), it finally succeeded in the first quarter of 2014, when its forceful market intervention drove down the renminbi’s exchange rate to discourage carry trades. Now, however, the PBOC is facing an even more difficult challenge, as seemingly irreversible depreciation expectations undermine economic stability at a moment when China can least afford additional uncertainty.


Because the 2014 intervention coincided with the weakening of China’s economic fundamentals, it ultimately amounted to pushing on an opening door. Instead of providing credible resistance to upward pressure on the exchange rate, as intended, it triggered an outright reversal, with depreciation expectations beginning to creep into foreign-exchange markets.


Thus, in the second quarter of 2014, China recorded a capital-account deficit for the first time in decades. And by the first quarter of 2015, that deficit more than offset the current-account surplus, meaning that China registered its first international balance-of-payments deficit in recent memory.


Nonetheless, given the size of China’s foreign-exchange reserves, markets remained confident that the PBOC could fix the renminbi exchange rate at whatever level it wanted, regardless of China’s external balance-of-payments position. As a result, depreciation expectations were not strong.


Then, last August, the PBOC lowered the renminbi central parity rate by 1.9%, perhaps in response to an International Monetary Fund report encouraging China to align the parity rate more closely with the market rate. The move roiled markets and intensified depreciation expectations. The PBOC quickly intervened to avert a panic by halting the depreciation, but it was too late: expectations of further renminbi weakening became firmly established in the market.


As these expectations drive an increasing amount of capital out of China, thereby intensifying depreciation pressure, the PBOC continues to intervene in the foreign-exchange market, often in unpredictable ways (in order to discourage speculation). As a result, the PBOC has de facto adopted a crawling-peg exchange-rate regime.


While a crawling-peg system can eliminate short-term depreciation expectations, thereby reducing the associated capital outflows, it cannot eliminate depreciation expectations in the more distant future, let alone reduce capital outflows unrelated to depreciation expectations. In fact, the crawling peg encourages some kinds of capital outflows, such as carry trade unwinding, the dollarization of household accounts, and withdrawal by portfolio investors. Meanwhile, China’s economic fundamentals continue to worsen.


All of this has forced the PBOC to spend a huge amount of China’s foreign-exchange reserves – more than $500 billion in 2015 alone – to keep the level of renminbi depreciation vis-à-vis the US dollar within 5%. At this rate, those hard-earned foreign-exchange reserves will soon be exhausted. That is not an option.


Recognizing the challenge at hand, the PBOC has been allowing the renminbi to fall, slowly but surely, since November. But while this “stealth devaluation” worked for a while, market participants decided at the beginning of this year to dump their renminbi again.


The PBOC now has three options: it can stop all interventions and let the renminbi float; link it to a basket of currencies; or peg it tightly to the US dollar, as it did during the Asian financial crisis of 1997. So far, however, the PBOC has offered no indication of its plans, beyond the continuation of its current renminbi-sustaining policy.


In my opinion, the PBOC should reinforce the Chinese government’s market-oriented reform plans and allow the renminbi to float. China is still running a large current-account surplus and a long-term capital-account surplus, and it has not fully liberalized its capital account; so the chances are good that the renminbi would not fall too far or for too long.


Moreover, even if the renminbi did experience a double-digit depreciation, China would not be thrust into financial crisis. After all, the country’s stock of corporate external debt is not too large; the currency mismatch within Chinese banks is small; and inflation is just above 1%. To bolster such financial buffers, China must enforce existing capital controls much more strictly.


Nonetheless, there remains the possibility of a market panic, with all of the uncertainty that such an episode implies. Given this, the PBOC could engineer a transition during which the renminbi is pegged to a basket of currencies, with an adjustable central parity rate and a wide fluctuation band of 7.5% or even 15%. It could choose not to announce the (very wide) fluctuation band, so that investors, judging that the renminbi had fallen far enough, might begin to purchase the currency before it actually reached the floor, thereby stabilizing the exchange rate before the PBOC was forced to spend more foreign-exchange reserves.


This year will be another difficult one for China. But the situation is far from dire. With the right policy mix, China should be able to stabilize its currency and foreign-reserve position, and return to a sustainable growth path.


(本文仅代表作者个人观点,不代表CF40立场)



往期文章精选

余永定、张斌、张明:克服贬值恐惧 篮子汇率宽幅波动


利率、汇率调整到位后,印度发生了什么?


金融业“营改增”的优选方案


管涛:当前做好汇率预期管理更重要


中企投资巴基斯坦的风险因素与应对策略



中国金融四十人论坛

  “中国金融四十人论坛”(CF40)是一家非官方、非营利性的独立智库,专注于经济金融领域的政策研究。论坛成立于2008年4月12日,由40位40岁上下的金融精锐组成,即“40×40俱乐部”。   本智库的宗旨是:以前瞻视野和探索精神,致力于夯实中国金融学术基础,研究金融领域前沿课题,推动中国金融业改革与发展。

  关注中国金融四十人论坛,请长按下方二维码:



您可能也对以下帖子感兴趣

文章有问题?点此查看未经处理的缓存